Designing an industrial strategy
We agree both with analysts who think of industrial policy as the construction of an appropriate ‘institutional architecture’ and those who see it as a more purposeful process of pushing an economy in a desired direction,[1]as industrialization in developing countries is unlikely just to occur through a spontaneous, decentralized process. Nonetheless, any purposeful industrial strategy must be conscious of the need to construct solid institutions and organizations, or make use of any that already exist. Essential features of a desirable institutional architecture include high-level support for key ministries and agencies; functioning coordination mechanisms across ministries; bureaucratic integrity, preventing the capture of state officials by business; and adaptability, so that agencies do not become beholden to courses of action that have proved unfruitful.
It is unlikely that even among highly committed governments there will be the political capital and administrative capacity required to follow these principles across the board. Therefore, it is necessary to give preference to priority areas for the government’s industrialization objectives.
Industrial Policy and State coordination – the case of post-apartheid South Africa
The period since the end of apartheid has witnessed a reduction in the share of manufacturing in the economy of South Africa, Africa’s most industrialized economy. This trend has taken place despite the government’s declared commitment to industrialization, and comes on the back of a number of coordination failures that have hampered the effectiveness of existing industrial policy.
By 1996, three different government departments had published conflicting economic policy frameworks, all of which were eventually dropped[1] : the National Growth Path Framework, developed by the Reconstruction and Development Planning office of the Presidency; a social plan produced by the Labour Department’s Presidential Labour Market Commission; and the Treasury’s Growth, Employment and Redistribution (GEAR) strategy. The National Treasury also opposed the industrial policy plans of the Department for Trade and Industry (DTI), as they were contrary to ‘picking winners’.
Similarly, the National Industrial Policy Framework adopted by the government in 2007 was rendered ineffectual by a lack of budgetary support – as funding for DTI programmes declined from 1994 onwards – and inconsistency with macroeconomic policies focused on targeting inflation, ignoring the problems caused by oscillations in relative prices[2] . More generally, industrial policy in South Africa has been marked by fragmentation. For instance, Hausmann, Rodrik and Sabel[3] describe the DTI’s Customized Sector Programs (CSP) as “a collection of very disparate industrial policy initiatives grouped under a common rubric.” Moreover, there is little coordination between DTI programmes and other government departments, despite official rhetoric in favour of industrialization.
At the roots of the coordination problems of industrial policy in South Africa is the fragmentation of the ruling party, its focus on other issues, and capture by special interests such as organized labour and the ‘mineral-energy complex’. These translate into policies that continue to favour the mining sector. In addition, labour and large business interests effectively are in a rent-sharing agreement that keeps high wages for insiders, inhibits employment creation, and hampers investment in manufacturing.
[1] Haroot, Bhorat, Aalia Cassim and Alan Hirsch (2014) – “Policy co-ordination and growth traps in a middle-income country setting: the case of South Africa” WIDER Working Paper 2014/155
[2] Simon Roberts (2014) – “Industrialization Strategy” in Haroon Bhorat, Alan Hirsch, Ravi Kanbur and Mthuli Ncube, The Oxford Companion to the Economics of South Africa Oxford: Oxford University Press
[3]Ricardo Hausmann, Dani Rodrik and Charles F. Sabel (2007) – “Reconfiguring Industrial Policy: A Framework with an Application to South Africa”
Some principles of institutional design:
Setting up well-functioning public organizations with power over an adequate number of policy areas.
Building pilot agencies with a coordinating function.
Establishing effective business-government communication by strengthening business associations and designing business-government councils.
Establishing review mechanisms that allow the government to respond to changing conditions on the ground.
Our project aims to collaborate with national governments in elaborating an industrial strategy, including goals and priority areas, while also thinking about setting up appropriate institutional mechanisms. Below we enumerate the steps of such an industrial strategy. In parallel with these steps, governments must pay attention to design agencies that support their industrial strategy, are feasible in view of current state capabilities, and can operate effectively in a given political context.
[1] For an outline and discussion on the two positions, see Lippolis and Peel (2018) – “Issues in Industrial Policy Design and Implementation” Background Paper for Programme on Rethinking African Paths to Industrial Development. Blavatnik School of Government and Centre for the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford.
Political economy analysis
Do leaders have the power to create new organizations and invest in industrialization at a large scale? Or is it better to focus on particular sectors? Or is the country at a low level of institutional development and the best option is to come up with creative institutional arrangements? Recognising weaknesses and limitations in state capabilities and political space for action is crucial here.
Setting objectives
The government has to determine what its aims are. What is the relative importance of growth, employment, and reduction of inequalities? At this stage it is important to think of political grievances that industrial policy must redress or that risk derailing it, such as regional, ethnic and class inequalities.
Diagnostics
Includes economy-wide constraints, sectoral priorities and within-sector constraints. Here leaders should also survey existing state capabilities, identifying areas where they are strong and assessing the prospects of improving them where they are not, while recognising limitations in what can be achieved
Implementing horizontal policies
Ideally at the economy-wide level, but given limited resources, prioritization will be necessary for some policies. These should focus on the critical constraints on economy-wide growth identified at the diagnostics stage.
Implementing vertical policies
Will depend on obstacles identified through sectoral diagnostics and communication with businesspeople.